We
got some comments a week or so ago when we started the just-finished series on
the Greek debt crisis. While no doubt
well-intentioned, however, the comments were based on misconceptions about
money, credit, banking, and finance, as well as the facts of history, that made
it impossible to respond. Still, we
tried.
Malthus: puzzled by Say's Law |
While
there were a great many problems with the specifics of the comments, the
underlying problem was that the commentator didn’t realize that money is
anything that can be used to settle a debt.
Money is thus a tool, as explained in Say's Law of Markets, especially
in Say's first letter to Thomas Malthus.
The commentator
seemed to think that the amount of money creates exchanges of goods and services,
while in strict fact, it is exchanges that create money. He also didn’t
understand either what banks are (or the different types of banks) or the
proper function of a central bank, failing to distinguish between banks of
deposit, issue (circulation), and discount.
Just one example of his slightly distorted history, he claimed the Chinese were the first to use paper money. Strictly speaking, and as far as we know, this is correct: the Chinese were the first to use paper in their creation of negotiable instruments.
Just one example of his slightly distorted history, he claimed the Chinese were the first to use paper money. Strictly speaking, and as far as we know, this is correct: the Chinese were the first to use paper in their creation of negotiable instruments.
Chinese paper money: not the first. |
Prior
to the Chinese, however, for thousands of years people used clay, wood,
papyrus, parchment, leather (the Roman Senate financed part of the war effort
during the Punic Wars using bills of credit written on leather), — anything on
which a contract could be recorded. The vast bulk of documents that
survive from the ancient world are not literature, but “money” in the form of
bills of exchange, letters of credit, promissory notes, bank drafts, and bills
and notes of all kinds. These forms of money preceded coined money — and
the use of paper — by millennia.
Notes and bills, “document money,” are not a substitute for coin, rather, coin is a substitute for bills and notes, which themselves are substitutes for (symbols of) the “underlying,” that is, the present value of the marketable good or service conveyed in the contract as consideration.
Notes and bills, “document money,” are not a substitute for coin, rather, coin is a substitute for bills and notes, which themselves are substitutes for (symbols of) the “underlying,” that is, the present value of the marketable good or service conveyed in the contract as consideration.
Essentially,
a mortgage or a bill of exchange is a symbol of the present value of an
existing or future marketable good or service, respectively, while coins and
banknotes are symbols of a mortgage or bill of exchange. When government
gets into the act and emits bills of credit, it uses its own liability and
promise to collect taxes in the future instead of assets to back its
liabilities.
Irving Fisher, developed MxV=PxQ |
It
was clearly evident that the commentator held to the currency principle. In jargonese, that means that he believed
that in the Quantity Theory of Money Equation, M x V = P x Q, where M is the
quantity of money, V is the average number of times each unit of currency is
spent in a period, P is the price level, and Q is the number of transactions,
“M” is the “independent variable.”
That
means that, in his view, the amount of money in the economy has a direct effect
on P, Q, and V. The problem is that,
yes, M does have an effect on the other variables if you change M without
changing anything else . . . but it’s an indirect effect, and you can’t predict
what the effect is going to be with any certainty.
In
the banking principle, M is the only dependent
variable in the equation. That means
that the market or some other agency determines P, Q, and V, and the amount of
money is determined by the needs of the economy directly by these
variables. Assuming that all money is
created by issuing mortgages and bills of exchange, then changing P, Q, or V will
automatically and directly result in a corresponding change in M.
We
tried to explain this to the commentator so he would understand our
response. We explained the definitions
we use and the meanings of the principles even before we attempted to respond.
The
commentator came back and denied that he adhered to any principle at all, but
especially did not go by the currency principle. Since that was demonstrably false, we decided
not to bother trying to respond. If you
reject our principles, you won’t understand what we say, and if you reject your own principles, chances are you
won’t understand what you’re saying, either.
#30#